Print This Post Print This Post

The Missing Link

March 25, 2016

The most important fundamental driver of the gold market that hasn’t yet begun to move in a gold-bullish direction is the US yield curve, represented on the following chart by the 10yr-2yr yield spread. The yield curve is bullish for gold when it is getting steeper, as indicated by a rising 10yr-2yr yield spread (a rising line on the following chart). With the 10yr-2yr yield spread having recently made a new 8-year low and not yet shown any sign of reversing upward, the yield curve remains unequivocally gold-bearish.

yieldspread_blog_250316

The yield curve is also one of the most important economic indicators to not yet warn of a US recession. Note that contrary to popular opinion it isn’t an inversion of the yield curve (the 10yr-2yr yield spread dropping below zero) that warns of a recession, it’s a trend reversal from flattening to steepening after the yield-spread has fallen to a multi-year low.

Based on what happened over the past 50 years, a trend reversal in the yield spread is not a prerequisite for a gold bull market. As long as sufficient other fundamental drivers (e.g. credit spreads and the real interest rate) are gold-bullish it is possible for gold to commence a bull market in the absence of a supportive yield curve. This is exemplified by the bull market that began during 1976-1977. However, it would be unprecedented for a US recession to begin in the absence of an upward reversal in the 10-yr-2yr yield spread.

Print This Post Print This Post

The great inflation-unemployment trade-off stupidity

March 22, 2016

The 15th March Financial Times article that I rubbished in a blog post last week contained the comment: “the 1970s ‘Phillips Curve’ trade-off between unemployment and inflation is alive and well“. Unbeknownst to me at the time, since I never tune in to Federal Reserve press events, Fed chief Janet Yellen said almost exactly the same thing at the 17th March post-FOMC press conference. Specifically, she said: “The Phillips Curve is alive“, by which she meant the purported trade-off between general price inflation and unemployment (the idea that lower unemployment generally comes at the cost of higher inflation and lower inflation generally comes at the cost of higher unemployment) was becoming an important consideration. This statement reveals cluelessness in three different ways.

First, the Phillips Curve and the theory behind it does NOT suggest that there is a trade-off between unemployment and general price inflation. In fact, it says nothing whatsoever about the relationship between general price inflation and unemployment. The Phillips Curve is about the relationship between changes in REAL wages and changes in employment. It is basic supply-demand stuff. As explained by John Hussman back in 2011:

Phillips demonstrated a principle that is well-known to every economist: very simply, when a useful resource becomes scarce, its price tends to increase relative to the prices of other goods and services. That finding doesn’t need all sorts of intellectual contortions or modeling tricks to make it “work,” because it is one of the most basic laws of economics.

The true Phillips Curve, then, is a relationship between unemployment and real wages. When workers are scarce, wages tend to rise faster than the general price level. When workers are plentiful, wages tend to rise slower than the general price level.

Second, the empirical data clearly show that there is no consistent relationship between general price inflation and unemployment. The above-linked Hussman article includes the relevant evidence in chart form. That is, even if the misrepresentation and misuse of the Phillips Curve is put aside, no economist who has bothered to check the historical data could believe in the inflation-unemployment trade-off.

Third, any half-decent economist would realise that there is no basis under sound economic theory for there to be a trade-off between unemployment and “price inflation”. The simple reason is that economic progress, which usually leads to more opportunities for employment, results from increasing productivity and, all else being equal, would therefore tend to be associated with a falling, not a rising, general price level. That is, all else being equal there should be a positive correlation rather than a trade-off between unemployment and “price inflation”. Of course, in the real world all is not equal, first and foremost because the central bank is constantly manipulating prices. Based on the fatally flawed models to which they are committed, central banks try to curtail the decline in the general price level that would naturally stem from economic progress. In doing so they falsify the price signals upon which the market economy relies, thus creating greater inefficiency.

The nicest thing I can say about Janet Yellen is that she doesn’t appear to be as stupid and dangerous as Mario Draghi, although I’ll change my mind about that if she ends up taking the Fed down the negative-interest-rate path.

Print This Post Print This Post

Are speculators too optimistic about the gold price?

March 21, 2016

Jordan Roy-Byrne recently posted an interesting video discussing gold’s Commitments of Traders (COT) data. The video was a response to numerous articles warning that the COT situation was flashing a danger signal. I agree with Jordan’s interpretation, which is that the COT data are probably not predicting a large decline in the gold price.

The main point of the above-linked video is similar to a point I’ve made numerous times in TSI commentaries over the years. The point is that there are no absolute benchmarks when it comes to sentiment indicators in general and the COT situation in particular (the COT reports are nothing more than sentiment indicators). A level that constitutes an ‘overbought’ warning in a bear market will usually not be applicable in a bull market, in that during a multi-year bullish trend the market will tend to become more ‘overbought’ and stay ‘overbought’ for longer. Of particular relevance, the speculative net-long position in gold futures that coincides with a short-term price top will generally reach much higher levels during a bull market than during a bear market. In fact, by the time a bull market has been in progress for 2-3 years the levels that marked short-term ‘overbought’ extremes during the preceding bear market could now mark short-term ‘oversold’ extremes.

In other words, sentiment must be considered within the context of the long-term price trend.

Unfortunately, in the early part of a new long-term trend there is usually no way to know, for sure, that the trend has changed. In gold’s case there is evidence that a cyclical bull market has begun, but the evidence is not yet conclusive. That’s why it is prudent to take information such as the COT data at face value.

I view gold’s current COT situation, which is reflected on the following chart from Sharelynx.com, as a valid warning that short-term downside risk is at least as high as the remaining short-term upside potential. At the same time I realise that if gold has entered a new cyclical bull market then the speculative net-long position (the red bars on the chart) is going to get much larger within the coming two years.

goldCOT_210316

Print This Post Print This Post

Have economists learned anything since the 1970s?

March 18, 2016

Judging by Ambrose Evans-Pritchard’s 15th March article in the Financial Times, which rehashes the most popular economics-related fallacies of the 1970s, the answer to the above question is a resounding NO.

Here’s an excerpt from the article that neatly encapsulates the ideas that were widely believed by economists during the 1960s-1970s, that were shown to be false during the 1970s, and that are now apparently again accepted as true:

Every major downturn since the First World War has been caused by the Fed, determined to snuff out inflation as the credit cycle matures. Expansions rarely die of old age. They are killed.

There may have been other factors in each historical episode — the oil shocks of the 1970s, or the first Gulf War in 1991 — but the Fed has been the determining catalyst each time.

Mr Fischer could hardly have been clearer. He spelled out why the 1970s ‘Phillips Curve’ trade-off between unemployment and inflation is alive and well, and an implicit warning that prices could soon take off since the labour market is clearly approaching the electric fence of Milton Friedman’s NAIRU (non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment).

The fact is that the Fed does cause severe economic downturns, but not by tightening monetary policy. In the real world, every boom that occurs on the back of money-pumping and interest-rate suppression contains the seeds of its own destruction. The reason is that the falsification of prices resulting from the central bank’s efforts to stimulate economic activity leads to widespread malinvestment.

Once the malinvestment occurs, a painful period of adjustment becomes inevitable. As Mises explained about 100 years ago, the only question is whether the adjustment begins sooner as a consequence of deliberately slowing the pace of money-pumping or later as a consequence of a collapse in confidence in the money. Politicians naturally want the adjustment to happen later (after the next election or, best of all, on somebody else’s watch), but the later it happens the more painful it will be.

It seems that Keynesian economic theories have to be totally discredited every generation, because regardless of how wrongheaded they are proved to be they always make a spectacular comeback. Furthermore, it’s not like what’s now commonly known as Keynesian Economics was invented by J.M.Keynes. In essence, all Keynes did was give his name, stamp of approval and incomprehensible language to ideas that had been tried to disastrous effect as far back as ancient Roman times.

It’s not hard to understand why these wrongheaded ideas inevitably get revived. They always recapture their lost popularity because they sound good at the most superficial level (they can sound like a way to provide free lunches for all) and because they seem to provide governments with an excuse to expand their reach.

Print This Post Print This Post

Death crosses are often golden and golden crosses are often deathly

March 15, 2016

A “death cross” is when the 50-day moving average (MA) goes from above to below the 200-day MA. According to conventional wisdom death crosses are bearish, but they often occur near short-term price lows and therefore tend to be bullish.

For example, over the past 5 years the S&P500 Index (SPX) has experienced three death crosses. The first occurred near the August-2011 price bottom, which turned out to be a wonderful time to buy. The second occurred near the August-2015 price bottom, which was last year’s low. The third occurred near the low in January this year. I’ll be surprised if the January low turns out to be the 2016 low, but it was followed by a tradable rally.

SPX_140316

A “golden cross” is when the 50-day moving average (MA) goes from below to above the 200-day MA. According to conventional wisdom golden crosses are bullish, but they often occur near short-term price highs and therefore have short-term bearish implications more than half the time.

For example, short-term tops in the gold price occurred near “golden crosses” in September-2012, March-2014 and July-2014. Also, it’s too soon to know for sure, but it seems that a golden cross marked a short-term top in the gold price during the first half of this month.

gold_140316

Death crosses tend to have short-term bullish implications because they often happen around the time that the market becomes stretched to the downside. Similarly, golden crosses regularly have short-term bearish implications because they often happen around the time that the market becomes stretched to the upside.

Print This Post Print This Post

Rules For Stock Speculation

March 14, 2016

Here are 21 rules/guidelines that I try to follow when speculating in the stock market. I don’t always follow them and in such cases I usually end up regretting it.

1. Every investment must pass the “Sleep Test”

An investment should not be so large that you lie awake at night worrying about it. To be a successful speculator or investor you must be able to remain relaxed and objective. An uncomfortably large investment or trade, although offering a potentially great return, can jeopardise your ability to remain objective and can thus lead to mistakes.

2. Avoid the emotions of hope, greed and fear

Hope is often associated with unrealistic expectations and causes an investor to cling to a losing position, magnifying the losses unnecessarily. Greed causes an investor to buy at the wrong time, such as near the peak of a rally, and to risk excessive amounts of money. Fear prevents an investor from buying at a time when the market presents the best opportunities to buy and prompts him to sell at the worst possible time (at the bottom of a correction or bear market).

3. A corollary to Rule 2 is: Treat your investing/trading as a business, not a Vegas-style gamble

This involves:

a) Checking your emotions at the door. You won’t be able to make objective decisions if you get excited by profits and/or depressed by losses.

b) Following an entry and exit plan for every stock you buy.

c) Not caring what happens to the price of a stock after you sell it. If you constantly worry that a stock will rocket higher after you sell then you will never be able to exit at an appropriate time.

d) Ignoring the cheerleaders. The cheerleaders (those commentators who become progressively more bullish the higher the price goes and who focus exclusively on the potential for huge rewards as if buying into the market right now were a sure path to great riches) tend to bring out the gambling spirit in their followers.

4. Use a disciplined risk-management approach at all times

It is difficult to own-up to a mistake. There is also usually the fear that if I sell now for a small loss the price will immediately rebound and I will have lost the opportunity to profit from the rise. After all, “hope springs eternal” and that stock that keeps dropping like a stone will one day soar like an eagle; all I need to do is be patient.

A systematic approach to risk management, which may or may not include ‘stop losses’, must be used to protect your investment capital. This is a hard lesson to learn and can usually only be learnt the hard way through experience.

5. Minimise the role of luck in your investing by playing a percentage game

Playing a percentage game encompasses the following guidelines:

a) Do not try to make a killing during any given year, but, instead, follow an approach designed to generate above-average returns over several years. In this way you might actually end up making a killing, but be aware that the vast majority of people who set out to get rich quick in the stock market end up a lot poorer.

b) Never plan to buy at the bottom or sell at the top. Instead, plan to buy on those occasions when the reward/risk ratio is high and to not buy, or to sell, on those occasions when it is low.

c) Take some money off the table during periods of extreme strength so you won’t feel pressured to sell during the periodic shakeouts.

d) Do some buying during the severe shakeouts that periodically occur in long-term bull markets. Note, though, that this will usually only be possible from a financial and/or an emotional standpoint if you previously took some profits into strength.

e) Never make whole-scale buy or sell decisions. Instead, scale into positions during weakness and scale out during strength, all the while maintaining exposure to the long-term bull market of the time.

f) Don’t ‘bet the farm’ on any single forecast. Forecasts, regardless of how well thought-out they appear to be, are just opinions, and any opinion can be wrong.

g) Don’t risk a large portion of your capital on any single stock. Regardless of how attractive a stock appears to be, acknowledge the fact that ‘stuff’ sometimes happens even to the best of companies.

6. Do your buying during those times when the fundamentals AND the price action are favourable

The fundamentals are favourable if the current price of the stock is low relative to the value of the underlying business, where the value of the underlying business is detemined by the company’s assets and growth prospects.

Examples of favourable price action include consolidations or basing patterns within longer-term upward trends.

7. Don’t focus on the profit/loss of a trade while the trade is on-going

Thinking about how much money you are making or losing on a trade while the trade is on-going may cause the emotions of fear and/or greed to influence your decisions. Have an exit plan for each stock and continue to monitor the fundamentals and the price action to determine whether to hold or to sell.

8. Make sure your exit plan for a stock is consistent with your entry plan

For example, if favourable price action was your main reason for buying a stock then you should exit if the price action turns unfavourable. In this case a reasonable approach could involve setting a protective stop just below a technical support level. However, if your decision to buy was based primarily on value considerations then it would make no sense to sell simply because the price became lower.

9. Remember that there are no absolute highs or lows

It is often the cheapest stocks that fall the furthest and the most expensive stocks that show the greatest price appreciation. Also, a price level that seems low or high today might appear the opposite in 12 months time.

10. Always maintain a substantial cash balance

You must always be in a position to take advantage of any opportunities that arise and the only way to do this is to always have significant cash reserves.

11. Close an event-based trade as soon as the anticipated event occurs

For example, let’s say a company you follow is about to announce its latest earnings. You expect the company to announce earnings that surprise on the upside and purchase the stock with the aim of taking a profit in the days following the announcement. If the company subsequently announces a result that does not exceed expectations you must immediately sell because the basis for your trade has proven to be false. If, however, the company does announce higher-than-expected earnings then you must sell within a few days of the announcement irrespective of the price action because this was your plan going into the trade. A disciplined approach will prevent short-term trades from becoming unwanted long-term investments.

12. Don’t be stingy when it comes to market information and stock buy/sell prices

The speculative investor does not day-trade and does not enter a position with the aim of taking a quick small profit. The timeframe for a trade will generally range from 1 month to 24 months and the goal will generally be to achieve a return of more than 30%. As such, it makes no sense to hold out for the final few percent when making a purchase or a sale.

Market- or stock-related information that increases your chances of investing/trading success is worth paying for.

13. Be aware that when the public is either extremely bullish or extremely bearish, the risk of a trend change is high

When the vast majority is extremely bullish then almost everyone who is going to buy has already bought and there is only one direction for the market to go, and that’s down. Similarly, when the vast majority is extremely bearish then almost everyone who is going to sell has already sold and there is only one direction for the market to go, and that’s up. Beware, though, that what constitutes a bullish or bearish extreme will differ depending on the long-term trend. For instance, sentiment can become more bullish and stay bullish for longer during a bull market than during a bear market.

14. Be patient

On average, you should not realistically expect to find more than two great opportunities per year to profit from market timing (sometimes there will only be one and there will seldom be more than three). As such, it pays to be patient and to wait for the major market reversals that usually accompany extremes in mass psychology. When these opportunities occur, the speculative investor must be financially prepared (refer to Rule 10) and psychologically prepared (refer to Rule 2) to take full advantage.

15. Remember and learn; don’t regret or blame

Take full responsibility for all of your investment decisions and never fall into the trap of blaming others when things go wrong. Losses are often learning experiences and can actually be money well spent if they prevent you from making the same mistake again, but if your reaction to a loss is to look outside yourself for someone/something to blame then you’ve learnt nothing from the experience and the money was wasted.

16. Keep yourself well-grounded

This encompasses the following:

a) Never complain about losses or brag about profits.

b) When the market is trending strongly higher and your stocks are going up every day remember that you are nowhere near as smart as you think you are; and during the severe corrections when every stock you own appears to be headed towards zero remember that you aren’t as dumb as you feel.

c) Be prepared to change your opinion if the facts change. In other words, don’t become wedded to any stock or to any market view.

d) Don’t act as if the current rally will be the last great money making opportunity. It won’t be.

e) Always keep your mind open to new ideas and analysis/evidence that contradicts your current view of the financial world. Most people are quick to embrace anything that meshes with their existing beliefs and to dismiss anything that contradicts these beliefs, which is why most people never see the signs of a trend change until it is too late.

17. Know the story behind every stock you buy

It is not enough to simply follow the recommendations in any newsletter because even if these recommendations are on-the-mark you won’t be able to buy or to hold in the amidst of a selling panic unless you have the confidence that stems from having a thorough understanding of the story.

18. Know yourself

For example, if you are someone who gets antsy and has trouble sleeping whenever the stocks you own make big moves, then don’t buy volatile stocks. Or if you know you are going to be too busy to fully understand the stories behind individual stocks then allocate most of your stock-market-related capital to ETFs and mutual funds.

19. Never use margin debt

NEVER buy stocks on margin. This is because as soon as you begin using margin debt you become a ‘weak hand’ — someone who would likely be forced to sell in reaction to a sharp price decline, that is, someone who would likely become a forced seller at a time when they should probably be buying.

20. Keep in mind that the ‘market’ does not know or care about your cost basis

When deciding whether to sell, hold or add-to a position in a stock, the price you paid for the stock is irrelevant. The market is under no obligation to raise the price of the stock to the point where you are able to exit at a profit or a reduced loss, and the fact that the price of a stock has fallen a long way from your purchase cost will never be a good reason to continue holding.

When deciding what to do with an existing position it is often helpful to first consider what you would do if you didn’t have the position. For example, if your current position in stock ABC has a market value of X$, think about what you would do if you had X$ of additional cash to invest and no position in stock ABC. In this case, would stock ABC be one of your top choices for investing the X$? If your answer is an unequivocal NO, then why are you continuing to hold the stock?

21. Understand that there is no such thing as “just a paper loss”

A loss is a loss, whether you take it or not. For example, if the price of a stock you own falls by 50%, then at that point you have lost 50% regardless of whether or not you lock-in the loss by selling. To view a loss as being somehow less serious if the position hasn’t yet been closed, or, worse still, to think that you haven’t actually incurred a loss at all until you sell, is both amateurish and financially-hazardous.

Print This Post Print This Post

Brazil Boom and Bust

March 10, 2016

Brazil, the ‘B’ in the BRIC acronym, was widely considered to be a model of emerging-market economic excellence during 2003-2011. Now it is widely considered to be an economic basket-case. What went wrong?

There are always many factors involved in a major economic turnaround, but for Brazil’s economy — and for many other economies over the past 15 years — the most important point to understand is that the impressive growth was not genuine; it was an artifact of rapid monetary inflation. Brazil’s government was just as corrupt and interventionist as ever during the period of impressive growth, but for a long time nobody noticed (or cared) because rapid domestic monetary inflation in parallel with a commodity bull market driven by rapid global monetary inflation created the illusion of increasing prosperity.

Brazil no longer has a monetary inflation problem. In fact, as depicted in the True Money Supply (TMS) chart below, it is now experiencing monetary DEFLATION.

And yet, Brazil’s central bank is still ‘tightening the monetary screws’. As illustrated by the following chart, it moved its targeted interest rate to an 8-year high of 14.25% in mid-2015 and has kept it there.

Brazil_intrate_020316

The current situation in Brazil underlines the problem of having monetary central planners. Even the smartest and most incorruptible of central planners will make the economy less efficient, because the right level for a price is the price that would exist in the absence of government or central-bank interference. However, monetary central planners tend to make matters even worse by reacting to backward-looking economic data and to the lagged effects of earlier policies.

In Brazil’s case, rather than acknowledging the extreme current tightness of monetary conditions and acting accordingly, the central bank is fixating on the CPI, which is, in turn, accelerating upward due to the lagged effects of the monetary inflation that happened years ago. This is a good example of how central bankers not only fail in their self-proclaimed mission to smooth-out the business cycle, but also greatly amplify the economic oscillations.

Brazil’s experience over the past 10 years is another in a long line of real-world demonstrations of Austrian Business Cycle Theory. Rapid monetary inflation and the lowering of interest rates results in an artificial boom, during which the GDP numbers look good at the same time as wealth-destroying investing mistakes are being made on a grand scale. The boom sets the stage for a bust, which wipes out all of the preceding gains and then some.

Print This Post Print This Post

Bad logic on trade

March 9, 2016

Although he could well be the least bad of the choices currently being offered to US voters (mainly because he would be less inclined towards “regime change” and bombing foreigners than the other choices), Donald Trump has made many ridiculous statements on the campaign trail. Examples include his proposal for a giant wall to stop Americans from escaping to Mexico (or the other way around, I can’t recall) and his idea about banning all Muslims from entering the US. The example that I’m covering in this post has to do with Trump’s comments on international trade. If he really believes what he is saying about trade deficits and tariffs (he might not — he might just be pandering to voters), then his economics knowledge is mindbogglingly inadequate.

I was prompted to write this post by the article linked HERE. This article reveals a surprisingly-good* understanding of economics. In particular, it makes the point that when it comes to trade, what’s commonly referred to as a “deficit” does not constitute a loss. A so-called deficit could actually be viewed as a benefit given that the side with the deficit is a net receiver of valuable goods in exchange for money that these days gets created out of nothing, although it makes more sense to view trade as a win-win situation.

By way of further explanation, if you shop at Walmart then you run a trade deficit with Walmart. Obviously, this is not a problem for you, otherwise you wouldn’t do it. It’s a case of you preferring some of the products on the shelves at Walmart over some of the cash in your wallet and Walmart preferring your cash to the products on its shelves. Walmart, in turn, runs a trade deficit with each of its suppliers for the same reason — one side of the transaction favours the product over the cash and the other side favours the cash over the product.

The point is that when a trade occurs it is illogical to think of the side that parts with money in exchange for goods or services as the loser.

Furthermore, despite the assertions of power-hungry politicians (is there any other kind?) to the contrary, the logic that applies to trading within national borders doesn’t magically cease to apply when the trade is conducted across borders. For example, if Bill and Fred are trading with each other, the trade doesn’t change from being a net positive or a non-issue when they are both in the US to a national problem when Bill steps across the border into Canada.

But isn’t it the case that every dollar that flows out of the country due to a trade deficit is a dollar less of spending within the domestic economy, which, in turn, leads to a weaker domestic economy and higher unemployment?

According to neo-Keynesian orthodoxy the answer is yes, but the correct answer is no. In reality, every dollar that flows out due to a trade deficit eventually returns as some form of investment. That’s why the $500B+ annual US trade deficit has not reduced the US money supply. As Joseph Salerno explains in a 2014 article, trade-deficit dollars get invested by foreigners in US stocks, bonds, real estate such as buildings and golf courses, and financial intermediaries like banks and mutual funds, with many of the dollars ultimately being lent to or invested in US businesses. These businesses then spend the dollars on paying wages and buying real capital goods like raw materials, plants, equipment and software.

The point is that the flow of spending in the US economy is not diminished by a negative trade balance, but merely re-routed. There will be a redirection of labor and capital out of export industries into industries producing consumer and capital goods for domestic use, with no net loss of jobs.

A net loss of jobs will, however, come about due to the policies such as tariffs and currency devaluation that are put in place to ‘fix’ a perceived trade-deficit problem. Tariffs simply impose an additional cost on a large group of consumers for the benefit of a small number of producers, resulting in a net loss to the economy by supporting inefficient businesses and reducing the amount that consumers can spend elsewhere.

In conclusion, the idea that the government should act to make it more expensive for its own citizens to purchase goods that are made in other countries is so transparently stupid it’s difficult for me to understand how such actions can be advocated with a straight face.

*I expect to find the application of good economic theory at sites such as mises.org and davidstockmanscontracorner.com, but I’m always surprised when I find it in articles at mainstream websites such as Yahoo Finance.

Print This Post Print This Post

Latest thoughts on Bitgold/Goldmoney

March 4, 2016

There have recently been far more than the normal number of interesting trading opportunities in the stock market, causing me to be busier than usual. This is due to the time involved in researching the larger number of opportunities with the aim of deciding what to present in the weekly TSI reports and what to do with my own money. I’m not complaining; this is just a roundabout way of explaining why I’ve posted less at the blog over the past two weeks, why this post on Goldmoney will not be as detailed as originally intended, and why blog posts could be sparse over the next few weeks. As a non-profit enterprise conducted mostly for fun, the blog necessarily plays second fiddle to preparing the TSI reports and planning/executing my own trades.

Getting to the point, here’s how I concluded my last post on Goldmoney (XAU.V): “At this stage I don’t have enough information to value Goldmoney, although I suspect that ‘reasonable value’ is a long way below the current price. I’ll post some updated thoughts when I have a clearer view of what the stock is worth, which might not be until February next year. In the meantime I’ll stay away. I have no desire to own the stock and, despite the apparent valuation-related downside risk, no desire to short the stock.” More information about Goldmoney’s financial performance has since become available.

I currently don’t have the time to go through the information in detail, but a cursory look at the company’s latest financial statements confirms my earlier impression that Goldmoney will have trouble making a profit. It made another loss in the final quarter of last year and continues to consume cash.

From the perspective of a Goldmoney user, the business is great. Customers can store gold, use gold as a medium of exchange and even take delivery of physical gold in manageable quantities, all at a low (or no) cost. From the perspective of a Goldmoney shareholder, however, the business is not so great. Of particular significance, unlike a mutual fund that charges a fee based on AUM (Assets Under Management), Goldmoney charges nothing to store its customers’ assets (gold bullion). This means that the larger the amount of Goldmoney’s AUM, the greater the net cost to the owners of the business (Goldmoney’s shareholders).

It’s important that under the current fee structure, Goldmoney will generally lose money on customers who use the service primarily for store-of-value purposes. This is where PayPal has a big advantage over Goldmoney. Nobody views their PayPal account as a long-term store of value. Instead, they view it as short-term parking for money to be spent, and when the money is spent PayPal usually gets a commission. This results in PayPal being very profitable, with earnings of US$1.2B (US$1.00/share) in 2015. Many of Goldmoney’s customers, however, view the service as a convenient way to store their physical gold. They don’t want to spend their gold, they want to save it.

Based on what I’ve seen to date I continue to believe that Goldmoney offers a great product, but is operating an inherently low-margin business deserving of a low valuation. Use the service, but don’t buy the stock.

XAU_030316

Print This Post Print This Post

Gold and Confidence

March 1, 2016

This post is a modified excerpt from a recent TSI report.

A point I’ve made many times in TSI commentaries over the years is that the major trends in gold’s relative value have nothing to do with what most people think of as “inflation” (a rising CPI). They are, instead, driven by shifts in how the financial establishment (the central bank plus the commercial banks) is perceived and by shifts in the perception of economic growth prospects. In more general terms, they are driven by shifts in confidence. There are times when a substantial decline in confidence is related to rising inflation expectations, but in developed economies there are more times when it isn’t. And even when it is, it’s not really the decline or the expected decline in the purchasing power of money that results in a greater desire to own gold; it’s the belief* that the stewards of the monetary system are losing control.

The happenings of the past three months constitute an excellent example. Inflation expectations were low when gold began to turn upward in December and if anything are even lower now, but over the past several weeks we had a very fast rally in the real gold price. It should be clear to any knowledgeable observer that the rally had absolutely nothing to do with fear of “CPI inflation”. Rather, it was driven by the combination of fear that the economically-destructive insanity known as Negative Interest-Rate Policy (NIRP) will spread to the US and fear of banking collapse in Europe.

Everything that the world’s most important central banks are doing is based on logical conclusions drawn from false premises. The false premise upon which interest-rate suppression is based is that economic growth is caused by borrowing and consumption. The reality is that saving is the foundation of sustainable economic growth. By pursuing policies that punish saving and reward borrowing, central banks set the scene for slower economic progress.

Now, progress-hindering monetary policy is not something new. It has been the order of the day for a very long time, but it has never before been taken to such extremes. Moreover, senior central bankers are making it crystal clear that they are not close to being done — that they are ready and willing to continue along the current path if the relentless beatings fail to lift morale — even though it is becoming more obvious by the day that the unconventional monetary policies have hurt far more than helped.

The upshot is that today’s central bankers are completely stupid, where stupid is defined as having an unwitting tendency towards self destruction**. Unfortunately, due to their immense power these men and women are taking entire economies along for the ride. The gradual dawning that this is happening is why gold is getting more popular.

*Central banks and governments never had genuine control, but there has been widespread BELIEF over the past several years in the abilities of central banks to create stronger economies.

**The Doug Casey definition.

Print This Post Print This Post